Dec 14, 2020

At a glance: Vertical agreements in India

Legal framework

Antitrust law

What are the legal sources that set out the antitrust law applicable to vertical restraints?

The Competition Act 2002 (the Competition Act) is the primary Indian law dealing with vertical restraints. Also, some sector-specific laws (such as the Telecom Regulatory Authority of India Act 1997, Electricity Act 2003 and Petroleum and Natural Gas Regulatory Board Act 2006) empower specially created sectoral regulators to enforce rules aimed at promoting competition in their respective sectors, which may extend to regulation of vertical restraints specific to telecoms, electricity or petroleum and natural gas.

Types of vertical restraint

List and describe the types of vertical restraints that are subject to antitrust law. Is the concept of vertical restraint defined in the antitrust law?

The Competition Act seeks to prohibit only such vertical restraints that cause, or are likely to cause, an appreciable adverse effect on competition in India. It contains an inclusive list of vertical agreements that may be prohibited only if, upon an investigation, the Indian antitrust regulator, the Competition Commission of India can establish that they cause, or are likely to cause, an appreciable adverse effect on competition in India. The types of vertical restraints expressly identified in the Competition Act include:

> tie-in arrangements: a purchaser of goods is required to purchase any other goods as a condition of purchase;
> exclusive supply agreements: which restrict, in any manner, the purchaser from acquiring or otherwise dealing with the goods of the seller or any person;
exclusive distribution agreements: which limit, restrict or withhold the supply of goods or allocate any area or market for the disposal or sale of goods;
> refusal to deal: which restricts, or is likely to restrict, by any method, the person or persons from or to whom goods are bought and sold; and
> resale price maintenance: any agreement wherein goods are sold on the condition that the resale price shall be the price stipulated by the seller, unless clearly stated that prices lower than those prices may be charged.

Legal objective

Is the only objective pursued by the law on vertical restraints economic, or does it also seek to promote or protect other interests?

The Competition Act seeks to prohibit vertical restraints that cause or are likely to cause an appreciable adverse effect on competition in India – with the larger objective of promoting and sustaining competition in markets. That said, while assessing whether a vertical restraint may cause an appreciable adverse effect on competition, the Competition Commission of India is quite likely to examine its impact on consumers’ interests as well. In practice, on several occasions the Competition Commission of India has refused to entertain consumer disputes presented under the guise of competition complaints (eg, Akhil R Bhansali v Skoda Auto India Pvt Ltd (Case No. 44 of 2017)).

Responsible authorities

Which authority is responsible for enforcing prohibitions on anti-competitive vertical restraints? Where there are multiple responsible authorities, how are cases allocated? Do governments or ministers have a role?

The Competition Commission of India (CCI) is the primary authority responsible for enforcing the prohibitions on anti-competitive vertical restraints across all sectors. In its review of vertical restrictions, the CCI is assisted by its investigative arm – the Director General. Decisions of the CCI may be contested before the National Company Appellate Tribunal (NCLAT), and decisions of the NCLAT may then be contested before the Supreme Court of India.

The political executive has no role to play in the substantive review of competition cases, including on vertical restraints. However, the government has the power to exempt any class of enterprises or agreements from the application of the Competition Act, issue directions to the CCI on policy issues and even supersede the CCI if it fails to perform its functions.

Additionally, certain sectoral regulators in India also enforce rules that are aimed towards promoting competition in their respective sectors.

Jurisdiction

What is the test for determining whether a vertical restraint will be subject to antitrust law in your jurisdiction? Has the law in your jurisdiction regarding vertical restraints been applied extra-territorially? Has it been applied in a pure internet context and if so, what factors were deemed relevant when considering jurisdiction?

Any vertical restraint that causes, or is likely to cause, an appreciable adverse effect on competition in India is prohibited. The Competition Commission of India (CCI) can assume jurisdiction over enterprises located outside India, so long as the vertical restrictions imposed by such enterprises impact competitive conditions in India. The CCI often probes enterprises domiciled outside India. For example, in 2011, the CCI dismissed allegations of vertical restrictions allegedly imposed by Intel Corporation (a Delaware corporation) and its Indian subsidiary by fixing targets and incentives, restricting distributors from dealing with competitors’ products and determining the resale price for their distributors. Even in a pure internet context, the CCI will have jurisdiction to assess extraterritorial vertical restrictions if it considers such restrictions to impact the conditions of competition in India.

Agreements concluded by public entities

To what extent does antitrust law apply to vertical restraints in agreements concluded by public entities?

The prohibition on vertical restraints applies to all ‘enterprises’, including public entities performing non-sovereign economic functions. Sovereign functions of the government include activities of the government dealing with atomic energy, currency, defence, space, etc. In other words, if a public entity is engaged in an economic activity, its conduct would be subject to scrutiny under the Competition Act.

The Competition Commission of India (CCI) has indeed assessed allegations of vertical restraints against public undertakings. For instance, the CCI while examining whether the Indian Oil Corporation Limited (and two other state-owned oil and gas companies (together, PSUs) had imposed restrictive vertical conditions allowing the successful bidders to receive 40 per cent of their total income in the form of fleet and loyalty cards that were usable at the petrol pumps of these PSUs. The CCI found this condition to be commercially justifiable, primarily on account of bona fide requests for such loyalty cards from the bidders themselves (XYZ v Indian Oil Corporation Ltd (Case No. 5 of 2018)). Recently, the CCI closed an investigation against the Commissioner Department of Excise, Entertainment and Luxury Tax as it found it to be a department of the government whose functions falls within the realm of public policy and not engaged in any economic activity. (United Breweries Limited v the Commissioner, Department of Excise, Entertainment and Luxury Tax (Case No. 22 of 2019)).

Sector-specific rules

Do particular laws or regulations apply to the assessment of vertical restraints in specific sectors of industry (motor cars, insurance, etc)? Please identify the rules and the sectors they cover.

The prohibition on anti-competitive vertical agreements applies to all enterprises, regardless of the sectors in which they operate. Sectoral regulators such as the Telecom Regulatory Authority of India and the Central Electricity Regulatory Commission are also often tasked with enforcing rules aimed at promoting competition in the respective sectors. Recently, in the context of the telecom sector, the Supreme Court of India has clarified that if a sector-specific regulator (in this case, the Telecom Regulatory Authority of India) is already deciding certain jurisdictional issues, which are also integral for the Competition Commission of India (CCI) to reach a finding, the CCI must defer its inquiry until such issues are settled by the sector-specific regulators (CCI v Bharti Airtel Limited (Civil Appeals Nos. 11847-11851 of 2018)).

General exceptions

Are there any general exceptions from antitrust law for certain types of agreement containing vertical restraints? If so, please describe.

All vertical arrangements that cause, or are likely to cause, an appreciable adverse effect on competition in India are prohibited. There is no market share or materiality-based exemption. That said, inherent in the examination of whether a vertical restraint can cause an appreciable adverse effect on competition is the assessment of whether the entity under scrutiny enjoys some degree of market power. The Competition Commission of India often uses high market shares as a proxy for market power and often rejects allegations of vertical foreclosure where the market shares of the enterprises enforcing such restrictions are insignificant.

Also, two kinds of exceptions are applicable to vertical restraints:

> a holder of intellectual property may impose ‘reasonable restrictions’ that are ‘necessary’ for protecting any intellectual property rights (section 3(5) of the Competition Act); and
> the prohibition on vertical restraints does not restrict the right of any person to export goods from India – to the extent that such agreement relates exclusively to production, supply, distribution or control of goods or provision of services for such export.

Types of agreement

Agreements

Is there a definition of ‘agreement’ – or its equivalent – in the antitrust law of your jurisdiction?

The Competition Act defines an agreement to include any arrangement or understanding or action in concert whether or not such arrangement, understanding or action is formal or in writing; or whether or not such arrangement, understanding or action is intended to be enforceable by legal proceedings.

In order to engage the antitrust law in relation to vertical restraints, is it necessary for there to be a formal written agreement or can the relevant rules be engaged by an informal or unwritten understanding?

An agreement under the Competition Act need not be in writing – and includes any unwritten arrangement, understanding or action in concert. The Competition Commission of India (CCI)’s decisional practice suggests that an ‘understanding may be tacit, and the definition covers situations where the parties act on the basis of a nod or a wink’ (Re Director General (Supplies & Disposals) Directorate General of Supplies & Disposals, Department of Commerce, Ministry of Commerce & Industry, Government of India (reference Case No. 01 of 2012)). To establish an agreement, the CCI may consider circumstantial evidence, conduct or behaviour of the parties. For example, in 2015, the CCI penalised several automobile manufacturers for entering into anticompetitive vertical agreements with their authorised dealers, which restricted the dealers from selling automobile spare parts to third parties. Some of these agreements were in the nature of unwritten understandings between the original equipment manufacturers and their dealers, which effectively resulted in dealers refusing to sell spare parts on the open market (Shamsher Kataria v Honda Siel Cars India Ltd (Case No. 3 of 2011)).

Parent and company-related agreements

In what circumstances do the vertical restraints rules apply to agreements between a parent company and a related company (or between related companies of the same parent company)?

The Competition Act does not define the term ‘related company’. The term ‘group’ means two or more enterprises that, directly or indirectly, are in a position to:

>exercise 26 per cent or more of the voting rights in the other enterprise; or
appoint more than 50 per cent of the members of the board of directors in the other enterprise; or
>control the management or affairs of the other enterprise.

The Competition Commission of India recognises the single economic entity doctrine (SEE Doctrine) and does not typically subject agreements between enterprises forming part of the same group to the scrutiny of section 3 of the Competition Act (which includes the prohibition on vertical restraints). While allowing enterprises the benefit of the SEE Doctrine, the Competition Commission of India is likely to test de facto and de jure control exercised by a common parent over the management and affairs, including commercial decisions of the related companies.

Agent-principal agreements

In what circumstances does antitrust law on vertical restraints apply to agent-principal agreements in which an undertaking agrees to perform certain services on a supplier’s behalf for a sales-based commission payment?

The Competition Act does not prescribe any specific rules for agency agreements, and the prohibition on vertical restraints applies to all agreements between enterprises operating at different stages or levels of the production chain. Under the Indian Contract Act, an ‘agent’ means a person employed to do any act for another, or to represent another in dealing with third persons; and the person for whom such act is done is called the ‘principal’. Courts in India have often distinguished agent–principal relationships from purchaser–seller relationships. Therefore, agency presupposes lack of independence on the part of the agent and continued oversight of the principal on the actions deputed to the agent. A vertical arrangement within the meaning of the Competition Act arguably requires the arrangement to involve at least two or more independent entities (or principals). Accordingly, it appears unlikely for the standard rules on vertical restraints to apply to the restrictions imposed on an agent by its principal with the same rigour as principal–principal agreements.

In the context of digital markets and online platforms, the Competition Commission of India (CCI) has held that, while assessing vertical relationships, it will look into the substance rather than the form of the relationship. An enterprise providing any active/value added service (eg, logistics, warehousing, marketing, sales, etc) to the end-customer in availing the product or service involved will be deemed to be part of the vertical supply chain. In this case, the CCI rejected the argument that Snapdeal is an online platform and, therefore, not part of the vertical supply chain, as various distributors or dealers were using Snapdeal’s services while selling the products online (Jasper Infotech Private Limited (Snapdeal) v KAFF Appliances (India) Pvt Ltd (Case No. 61 of 2014).

Guidance on this subject also comes from the CCI’s analysis of arrangements between Uber and Ola (India’s two key technological platforms for cab aggregation) and their respective driver-partners. CCI’s latest decision involving these platforms dismisses allegations of resale price maintenance related to algorithmic price-setting by Uber and Ola. In its assessment, the CCI explained that, while the drivers are legally independent entities offering transportation services to the riders, they are effectively extensions or agents of Uber and Ola when they operate through their platforms. It found that there was no resale in this arrangement, because effectively, a single transaction takes place between the rider and Ola or Uber, which provide the composite service of the driver–rider matchmaking (Samir Agrawal v ANI Technologies Pvt Ltd (Case No. 37 of 2018)). Interestingly, in another closure decision involving these platforms, the CCI has suggested that incentives given by Uber and Ola to their prospective drivers (which were alleged to have exclusionary effects on competitors) do not fall under the definition of agreement under the Competition Act (Meru Travel Solutions v ANI Technologies Private Limited (Case No. 5-28 of 2017)).

Where antitrust rules do not apply (or apply differently) to agent-principal relationships, is there guidance (or are there recent authority decisions) on what constitutes an agent-principal relationship for these purposes?

The Competition Act does not prescribe any specific rules for agency agreements, and the prohibition on vertical restraints applies to all agreements between enterprises operating at different stages or levels of the production chain. Under the Indian Contract Act, an ‘agent’ means a person employed to do any act for another, or to represent another in dealing with third persons; and the person for whom such act is done is called the ‘principal’. Courts in India have often distinguished agent–principal relationships from purchaser–seller relationships. Therefore, agency presupposes lack of independence on the part of the agent and continued oversight of the principal on the actions deputed to the agent. A vertical arrangement within the meaning of the Competition Act arguably requires the arrangement to involve at least two or more independent entities (or principals). Accordingly, it appears unlikely for the standard rules on vertical restraints to apply to the restrictions imposed on an agent by its principal with the same rigour as principal–principal agreements.

Intellectual property rights

Is antitrust law applied differently when the agreement containing the vertical restraint also contains provisions granting intellectual property rights (IPRs)?

The holder of intellectual property may impose ‘reasonable restrictions’ that are ‘necessary’ for protecting any intellectual property rights recognised under the following Indian intellectual property rights statutes:

> the Copyright Act 1957;
> the Patents Act 1970;
> the Trade and Merchandise Marks Act 1958 or the Trade Marks Act 1999;
> the Geographical Indications of Goods (Registration and Protection) Act 1999;
> the Designs Act 2000; and
> the Semi-conductor Integrated Circuits Layout-Design Act 2000 (IPR Exemption).

The Competition Commission of India (CCI) appears to have been somewhat conservative in extending the benefit of IPR Exemption to entities imposing vertical restrictions. First, the CCI appears to have interpreted the ‘reasonable’ and ‘necessary’ conditions quite strictly and refused to extend the benefit of the IPR Exemption to vertical restrictions if the entity imposing such restrictions could protect its IPR by adopting a less restrictive method. Second, the CCI has read the text of the IPR Exemption literally and has refused to allow the benefit of the IPR Exemption if the right was not strictly characterised under the six laws identified in section 3(5) of the Competition Act.

Analytical framework for assessment

Framework

Explain the analytical framework that applies when assessing vertical restraints under antitrust law.

Vertical restraints are only prohibited if the CCI, upon an inquiry, concludes that they cause, or are likely to cause, an appreciable adverse effect on competition in India. To discharge this burden, the CCI is required to weigh the likely pro-competitive benefits against the potential anticompetitive harms arising from a vertical restriction. The likely anticompetitive harms that the CCI may examine include:

> creation of barriers to new entrants in the market;
> driving existing competitors out of the market; and
> foreclosure of competition by hindering entry into the market.

The pro-competitive benefits that the Competition Commission of India (CCI) is likely to examine to see if they offset the anticompetitive harms arising out of a vertical restraint, include:

> accrual of benefits to consumers;
> improvements in production or distribution of goods or provision of services; and
> promotion of technical, scientific and economic development by means of production or distribution of goods or provision of services.

Also, inherent in the CCI’s assessment of market foreclosure is an analysis of the market position of the enterprise enforcing the vertical restriction.

In practice, the CCI does not often entertain allegations where actual or likely market foreclosure is not demonstrated. For example, in 2017, the CCI dismissed allegations of vertical restraints and abuse of dominance in relation to power purchase agreements entered between NTPC Limited (an enterprise engaged in electricity generation) and Tata Power Delhi Distribution Limited (an electricity distribution company). The CCI was called upon to examine the exclusionary effects arising out of the long-term nature of power purchase agreements executed by NTPC Limited, specifically whether the lock-in restricted new enterprises from entering the electricity generation market. The CCI considered that significant investment made by the electricity generating companies naturally required that the power purchase agreements with distributors be for a longer duration. Moreover, since the tariffs are independently determined by the regulator for the electricity sector, there was little possibility of harm to consumers.

Market shares

To what extent are supplier market shares relevant when assessing the legality of individual restraints? Are the market positions and conduct of other suppliers relevant? Is it relevant whether certain types of restriction are widely used by suppliers in the market?

The Competition Act does not expressly require the Competition Commission of India (CCI) to consider the market share of the supplier while assessing vertical restraints. That said, the CCI typically only finds vertical restrictions to raise concerns when they are enforced by enterprises enjoying some degree of market power. On several occasions, the CCI has summarily rejected allegations of vertical restraints where the suppliers’ market shares were insignificant. The CCI dismissed allegations of resale price maintenance against manufacturers of Vivo mobile handsets in India on account of low (and declining) market shares, low turnover and high degree of inter-brand competition in the Indian smartphone market (Tamil Nadu Consumer Products Distributors Association v Fangs Technology Private Limited (Case No. 15 of 2018)). Equally, the CCI has considered the presence of other players in the market to infer that inter-brand competition in the fast-moving consumer goods sector was not affected (Ghanshyam Dass Vij v Bajaj Corp Ltd & Ors (Case No. 68 of 2013)).

Also, while the CCI may not exonerate anticompetitive restrictions purely on account of them being prevalent across the sector, it may consider the conduct of other enterprises in the industry to understand if such restrictions are objectively necessitated or justified by industry-specific concerns (eg, in an abuse of dominance and cartel context; see Faridabad Industries v Adani Gas Limited (Case No. 71 of 2012) and Shri Jyoti Swaroop Arora v Tulip Infratech Ltd (Case No. 59 of 2011)).

To what extent are buyer market shares relevant when assessing the legality of individual restraints? Are the market positions and conduct of other buyers relevant? Is it relevant whether certain types of restriction are widely used by buyers in the market?

While assessing vertical restrictions under the rule of reason framework, the CCI may consider the market shares of the buyer. For example, in Automobiles Dealers Association v Global Automobiles Limited & Ors (Case No. 33 of 2011), the CCI dismissed allegations of exclusive distributorship agreement because both parties to the agreement had insignificant market shares, which diminished the likelihood of market foreclosure.

Block exemption and safe harbour

Function

Is there a block exemption or safe harbour that provides certainty to companies as to the legality of vertical restraints under certain conditions? If so, please explain how this block exemption or safe harbour functions.

There are no block exemptions or safe harbour provisions relevant to the analysis of vertical restraints in India.

Types of restraint

Assessment of restrictions

How is restricting the buyer’s ability to determine its resale price assessed under antitrust law?

A resale price maintenance agreement that causes, or is likely to cause, an appreciable adverse effect on competition in India is prohibited. Fixing of the maximum resale price by a supplier is unlikely to raise resale price maintenance related concerns.

When compared to cases of abuse of dominance and cartel cases, the Competition Commission of India (CCI) has assessed a marginal number of vertical restraint cases. During the past nine years of the CCI’s enforcement, CCI appears to have reviewed approximately 17 cases involving resale price maintenance allegations. Of these, the CCI has imposed a penalty for resale price maintenance in only one case (M/s Fx Enterprise Solutions India Pvt Ltd and Anr v Hyundai Motor India Limited (Case Nos. 36 and 82 of 2014) (Hyundai)), initiated investigation in two cases (In re: Alleged anti-competitive conduct by Maruti Suzuki India Limited (Suo Motu Case No. 1 of 2019) (Maruti Suzuki India Limited) and Vishal Pande v Honda Motorcycle and Scooter India Private Ltd (Case No. 17 of 2017) (Honda Motorcycle)) and closed two after a more detailed investigation (Jasper Infotech Private Limited (Snapdeal) v KAFF Appliances (India) Pvt Ltd (Case No. 61 of 2014) and M/s ESYS Information Technologies Pvt Ltd v Intel Corporation (Case No. 48/2011)).

In Hyundai, the CCI found that Hyundai Motor India Limited’s (HMIL) prescription of maximum permissible discount to its dealers stifled intra-brand competition and resulted in higher prices for the consumers. The CCI noted that anti-competitive resale price restrictions could be achieved both directly or indirectly, for example, by fixing distribution margin, fixing maximum level of discount, making the grant of rebates or the sharing of promotional costs conditional on adhering to a given price level, linking a resale price to the resale prices of competitors, or using threats, intimidation, warnings, penalties, delay or suspension of deliveries as a means of fixing the prices charged by the buyer. However, this decision of the CCI has been set aside by the appellate court for defining the relevant market incorrectly and failing to independently verify the evidence collected by the Director General, among other reasons.

Relevantly, in the past, the CCI has refused to investigate allegations of resale price maintenance where the alleged restriction allowed the supplier to recommend the maximum retail price; and the distributor was only required to inform the supplier of its decision to allow a discount higher than stipulated (Shubham Sanitary Wares v HSIL Limited (Case No. 9 of 2015) (Shubham Sanitary Wares)).

In 2018, the CCI also initiated an investigation into allegations of imposing discount-related restrictions (enforced by levy of penalties for non-compliance) by Honda Motorcycle and Scooter India Private Ltd – finding on a prima facie basis that this could foreclose intra-brand competition among the dealers and increase prices (Honda Motorcycle). In 2019, on similar allegations, an investigation was also initiated against Maruti Suzuki India Limited.

A  CCI decision also highlights the importance of demonstrating ‘resale’ for a restriction to qualify as anti-competitive resale price maintenance. The CCI dismissed allegations that Ola’s and Uber’s (two of the largest radio taxi aggregators in India) practice of using algorithms to fix prices to be charged by their driver-partners to riders left no room for the drivers to charge a lower amount, which resulted in the maintenance of the floor price. The CCI found Uber’s and Ola’s services to be composite in nature – characterised by a single transaction between the rider and Ola or Uber and single generation of price. It also noted that such dynamic pricing often results in prices lower than that charged by independent taxi drivers, which also shows that there is no fixed floor price as such. Together, these factors precluded any resale price maintenance concerns (Samir Agrawal v ANI Technologies Pvt Ltd (Case No. 37 of 2018)).

Have the authorities considered in their decisions or guidelines resale price maintenance restrictions that apply for a limited period to the launch of a new product or brand, or to a specific promotion or sales campaign; or specifically to prevent a retailer using a brand as a ‘loss leader’?

To our knowledge, the CCI has not assessed a resale price maintenance restriction under any of these specific circumstances. That said, as resale price maintenance restrictions are assessed under the rule of reason test, the CCI is required to consider the efficiencies arising out them. Indeed, decisions relating to vertical restrictions have considered factors such as low market shares, limited duration of vertical restrictions and protection of brand image to negate the likelihood of market foreclosure (eg, Himalya International Ltd v Himalya Simplot Pvt Ltd (Case No. 92 of 2013); Shubham Sanitary Wares; and Ashish Ahuja v Snapdeal.com (Case No. 17 of 2014)).

Relevant decisions

Have decisions or guidelines relating to resale price maintenance addressed the possible links between such conduct and other forms of restraint?

In M/s Fx Enterprise Solutions India Pvt Ltd and Anr v Hyundai Motor India Limited (Case Nos. 36 and 82 of 2014) (Hyundai), the Competition Commission of India (CCI) briefly explored the possible links between resale price maintenance restrictions and cartels – and noted that a minimum resale price condition, if imposed at the behest of the distributors, would be particularly problematic because of the likelihood of similarity in prices at the level of the distributors – an outcome usually associated with cartels. That said, this decision of the CCI was later set aside by the appellate court.

Have decisions or guidelines relating to resale price maintenance addressed the efficiencies that can arguably arise out of such restrictions?

The CCI assesses resale price maintenance restrictions under the rule of reason framework, and is therefore obliged to look at any efficiencies arising out of vertical restrictions. To our knowledge, the CCI’s examination of resale price restrictions has not yet substantially dealt with the efficiencies arising out of such restrictions (but has often commented on the lack of any efficiencies or consumer benefit arising out of resale price maintenance).

Explain how a buyer agreeing to set its retail price for supplier A’s products by reference to its retail price for supplier B’s equivalent products is assessed.

To our knowledge, no decision of the CCI addresses a resale price restriction of this kind. That said, a resale price maintenance restriction could be achieved both directly or indirectly, including by linking a resale price to the resale prices of competitors (as noted by the CCI in Hyundai). Therefore, a price relativity agreement of this kind is likely to contravene the Competition Act if the CCI finds that it causes, or is likely to cause, an appreciable adverse effect on competition in India.

Suppliers

Explain how a supplier warranting to the buyer that it will supply the contract products on the terms applied to the supplier’s most-favoured customer, or that it will not supply the contract products on more favourable terms to other buyers, is assessed.

Recently, the Competition Commission of India (CCI) initiated an investigation in the online travel market, against various Online Travel Aggregators (OTAs), as it found MakeMyTrip (a provider of online intermediation services for booking of hotels) imposing across-platform parity agreements/most-favoured nation (MFN) clauses. Specifically, the MFN clause required the hotel partners to maintain room as well as price parity between platform and any other sale channel (other online travel aggregators, channels of the third parties and the hotel itself). Given the prima facie dominance or market power of MakeMyTrip in the market for online intermediation services for booking of hotels, the CCI directed the Director General to investigate this conduct (Federation of Hotel & Restaurant Associations of India v MakeMyTrip India Pvt Ltd & Ors (Case No. 14 of 2019)). The CCI investigation is currently ongoing.

An MFN arrangement is likely to be assessed by the CCI under the rule of reason framework and the CCI is likely to balance the pro-competitive and anticompetitive effects arising out of MFN arrangements and intervene if it finds the likelihood of appreciable adverse effect on competition in India.

Explain how a supplier agreeing to sell a product via internet platform A at the same price as it sells the product via internet platform B is assessed.

To our knowledge, no decision of the CCI addresses an MFN arrangement of this kind. E-commerce in India has recently gained popularity, and the online marketplaces in India are likely to remain competitive owing to increased internet penetration, competition in the telecommunications sector and significant investments in e-commerce. A retail MFN in the online environment, therefore, is likely to be assessed by the CCI under the rule of reason framework and the CCI is likely to balance the pro-competitive and anti-competitive effects arising out of MFN arrangements and intervene if it finds the likelihood of appreciable adverse effect on competition in India. Moreover, if the online platform lacks market power, the CCI may find it difficult to find market foreclosure resulting from retail MFNs.

Explain how a supplier preventing a buyer from advertising its products for sale below a certain price (but allowing that buyer subsequently to offer discounts to its customers) is assessed.

A minimum advertised price prescribed by a supplier may raise competition concerns if it causes, or is likely to cause, an appreciable adverse effect on competition in India. The CCI’s assessment is likely to focus on whether the minimum advertised price actually deters the buyer from reselling the products below the advertised price. If the buyer is able to sell the goods freely below the advertised prices, the risk of the market foreclosure is likely to be reduced significantly. The CCI has indeed refused to investigate resale price maintenance restrictions that were not absolute in nature – that is, where the condition allowed the supplier to recommend a maximum retail price and the distributor had to only inform the supplier of its decision to allow a discount higher than stipulated (Shubham Sanitary Wares v HSIL Limited).

Explain how a buyer’s warranting to the supplier that it will purchase the contract products on terms applied to the buyer’s most-favoured supplier, or that it will not purchase the contract products on more favourable terms from other suppliers, is assessed.

To our knowledge, no decision of the CCI addresses an MFN arrangement of this kind. Such an arrangement is likely to be assessed by the CCI under the rule of reason framework – similar to the analysis of a wholesale MFN, where the CCI is likely to balance the pro-competitive and anti-competitive effects arising out of MFN arrangements and intervene if it finds the likelihood of appreciable adverse effect on competition in India. Absent a monopsony situation, a buyer-imposed MFN is unlikely to adversely affect competition at the level of suppliers. Rather, the CCI may perceive a non-monopsony buyer-imposed MFN condition as beneficial to consumer interest.

Restrictions on territory

How is restricting the territory into which a buyer may resell contract products assessed? In what circumstances may a supplier require a buyer of its products not to resell the products in certain territories?

Restricting the territory into which a seller may sell a product will to be assessed by the Competition Commission of India (CCI) as an ‘exclusive distributor agreement’ and prohibited if it causes, or is likely to cause, an appreciable adverse effect on competition in India. While assessing territorial restrictions, the CCI is likely to consider the impact of such restrictions on intra-brand competition and inter-brand competition, and will also be guided by the market power of the enterprises involved. In its decisional practice, the CCI has recognised that territorial restrictions are often required to prevent free-riding, promote efficient management of sales of products, economic efficiency, etc (Ghanshyam Dass Vij v Bajaj Corp Ltd & Ors).

In a more recent case, the CCI did not find territorial restrictions in the distribution of mobile phones to be problematic because the customers of one sales region were not prevented from purchasing the relevant mobile phones from a dealer in another sales region, and there was no restriction on dealers from dealing with competing products in and outside the designated region (KC Marketing v OPPO Mobiles MU Private Limited (Case No. 34 of 2018)).

The CCI has also initiated an investigation into the restrictions imposed by Honda Motorcycle and Scooter India Private Limited (HMSIPL) for allegedly allocating areas to its distributors (Vishal Pande v Honda Motorcycle and Scooter India Private Ltd). HMSIPL was considered dominant in the market on a prima facie basis for the ‘manufacture and sale of scooters in India’.

Have decisions or guidance on vertical restraints dealt in any way with restrictions on the territory into which a buyer selling via the internet may resell contract products?

To our knowledge, the CCI has not assessed vertical territorial restrictions on internet sales. Those restrictions are likely to attract similar analysis as with non-internet sales.

Restrictions on customersExplain how restricting the customers to whom a buyer may resell contract products is assessed. In what circumstances may a supplier require a buyer not to resell products to certain resellers or end-consumers?

Restricting the customer to whom a buyer may sell a product may be prohibited as an ‘exclusive distribution agreement’ or ‘refusal to deal’ if it causes, or is likely to cause, an appreciable adverse effect on competition in India. For example, in Shamsher Kataria v Honda Siel Cars India Ltd (Case No. 3 of 2011), the Competition Commission of India (CCI) penalised various original equipment manufacturers for entering into vertical agreements with their authorised dealers that restricted the authorised dealers from supplying original spare parts to third parties. In Tamil Nadu Consumer Products Distributors Association v Fangs Technology Private Limited, the CCI did not identify any concerns with a clause that prevented distributors from making sales to corporate customers without prior intimation or written consent of the seller. Not only were there no documentary materials to support these allegations, but the CCI also seems to have appreciated that this restriction was necessary to ensure genuineness of the corporate sale (rather than to completely prevent them). Generally, if commercial reasons (such as for the launch of a new product or maintaining the integrity of the distribution channel) warrant imposition of a restriction of this kind, the CCI could consider the efficiencies arising out of such restrictions, as well as other factors that may reduce the likelihood of market foreclosure (such as low market shares or limited duration of the restriction).

Restrictions on use

How is restricting the uses to which a buyer puts the contract products assessed?

A vertical restraint restricting the use to which a buyer may put the contracted goods could be prohibited if the Competition Commission of India finds such restrictions to cause, or be likely to cause, an appreciable adverse effect on competition in India. To our knowledge, the Competition Commission of India does not appear to have assessed such a restraint as yet.

Restrictions on online sales

How is restricting the buyer’s ability to generate or effect sales via the internet assessed?

Restricting the buyer’s ability to sell via the internet could be prohibited if the Competition Commission of India (CCI) finds such restrictions to cause, or be likely to cause, an appreciable adverse effect on competition in India.

In 2018, the CCI assessed whether OPPO Mobile’s policy to prevent its distributors from selling OPPO products online was anticompetitive. Dismissing these concerns, the CCI found that OPPO smartphones were freely available in the market at competitive prices, including on major e-commerce websites, such as Flipkart, Snapdeal, Amazon and PaytmMall. This precluded any restriction of inter- or intra-brand competition (KC Marketing v OPPO Mobiles MU Private Limited (Case No. 34 of 2018)). A similar view was also taken by the CCI in M/s Karni Communication Private Limited & Anr v Haicheng Vivo Mobile (India) Private Limited (Case No. 35 of 2018).

In 2014, the CCI assessed allegations against Snapdeal.com (an e-commerce portal) and SanDisk Corporation (a manufacturer of electronic storage device). SanDisk persisted that only its authorised online channel partners shall sell its products through Snapdeal. Rejecting the allegations, the CCI noted that in a quality-driven market, the need to protect brand image justifies a business policy that discourages sale of products by unauthorised sellers (Ashish Ahuja v Snapdeal.com). In the following year, the CCI also examined allegations against various e-commerce websites (such as Flipkart or Amazon) that required certain products to be sold exclusively through select internet platforms to the exclusion of offline channels and competing internet portals. The CCI did not find any market foreclosure, because the products sold through these portals faced significant competitive constraints, and competition among e-portals was also thriving (Mohit Manglani v Flipkart India Private Limited (Case No. 80 of 2014)).

Have decisions or guidelines on vertical restraints dealt in any way with the differential treatment of different types of internet sales channel? In particular, have there been any developments in relation to ‘platform bans’?

To the best of our knowledge, the CCI does not appear to have assessed a restraint pertaining to differential treatment of different types of internet sales channels, specifically on ‘platform bans’. A concerted decision by suppliers to restrict the purchasers from reselling the products via online marketplaces may invite scrutiny for collusion.

Selective distribution systemsBriefly explain how agreements establishing ‘selective’ distribution systems are assessed. Must the criteria for selection be published?

A selective distribution system that restricts the supply of goods to enterprises other than those approved by the seller is likely to be assessed by the Competition Commission of India (CCI) as an ‘exclusive distribution agreement’ under the rule of reason framework.

In 2013, the CCI assessed a selective distribution system implemented by a state-owned oil and gas company that prescribed certain eligibility criterion for parties to qualify for a tender to transport liquefied petroleum gas cylinders. The CCI recognised that the enterprise had the liberty to procure services from the service providers it selected and that such legitimate business decisions do not warrant antitrust intervention (Keerthy Krishnan & Ors v Bharat Petroleum Corporation Limited & Ors (Case No. 8 of 2013)).

Also, to our knowledge, the CCI does not appear to have assessed whether the selection criteria in such cases ought to be published. However, if the selection criteria for such a system are discriminatory or one-sided, the CCI could assess them under the provisions relating to abuse of dominance.

Are selective distribution systems more likely to be lawful where they relate to certain types of product? If so, which types of product and why?

To our knowledge, the CCI does not appear to have assessed the legality of selective distribution systems using the type of product as a criterion. Certainly, the likelihood of market foreclosure may be reduced if the concerned product falls in a competitive market or is such that it warrants sale through a selective distribution system alone (high-end fashion goods, for example).

In selective distribution systems, what kinds of restrictions on internet sales by approved distributors are permitted and in what circumstances? To what extent must internet sales criteria mirror offline sales criteria?

Restrictions on internet sales in a selective distribution system are likely to attract similar analysis as with non-internet sales.

Has the authority taken any decisions in relation to actions by suppliers to enforce the terms of selective distribution agreements where such actions are aimed at preventing sales by unauthorised buyers or sales by authorised buyers in an unauthorised manner?

See the CCI’s decision in Ashish Ahuja v Snapdeal.com.

Does the relevant authority take into account the possible cumulative restrictive effects of multiple selective distribution systems operating in the same market?

The CCI may indeed take into account the possible cumulative restrictive effects of multiple selective distribution systems operating in the same market to see if they cause or are likely to cause an appreciable adverse effect on competition in India. In Shamsher Kataria v Honda Siel Cars India Ltd (Case No. 3 of 2011), the CCI comprehensively analysed anticompetitive conduct of the original equipment manufacturers ‘at the level of the macro automobile industry of India’. The CCI assessed the composite effects of the restrictive commercial arrangements instituted by all the automobile manufacturers, including warranty policies, dealer agreements, direct aftermarket sale of spare parts by suppliers, over-the-counter sales of spare parts by authorised dealers, and access to repair tools and technical information to independent repairers.

Has the authority taken decisions (or is there guidance) concerning distribution arrangements that combine selective distribution with restrictions on the territory into which approved buyers may resell the contract products?

The CCI in Ghanshyam Dass Vij v Bajaj Corp Ltd & Ors examined and dismissed allegations of territorial restrictions as well as maintaining an exclusive distribution system because the supplier enforcing the restrictions did not have sufficient market power, and the presence of other players ensured that inter-brand competition in the FMCG sector was not affected.

Other restrictionsHow is restricting the buyer’s ability to obtain the supplier’s products from alternative sources assessed?

Restricting the buyer’s ability to obtain the supplier’s products from alternative sources is likely to be assessed as an exclusive supply agreement or refusal to deal and is prohibited if it causes, or is likely to cause, an appreciable adverse effect on competition in India. The Competition Commission of India (CCI) examined a restriction of this nature in Shamsher Kataria v Honda Siel Cars India Ltd (Case No. 3 of 2011), where certain original equipment manufacturers restricted their authorised dealers from procuring spare parts from alternative sources. On account of such restrictions, the CCI found the automobile manufacturers to wield significant market power in the market for supply of genuine spare parts. The CCI found this restriction to have foreclosed independent repairers from the market for automobile repair services. More recently, the CCI initiated an investigation against Intel’s refusal to offer warranty service to consumers in India on products purchased by them from the parallel importers, who were authorised distributors of Intel abroad. The CCI observed that, given Intel’s dominance, this practice has the potential to lead to denial of market access to parallel importers and resellers, who are competitors of Intel’s Indian authorised distributors. (Matrix Info Systems Private Limited v Intel Corporation & Ors (Case No. 05 of 2019)).

How is restricting the buyer’s ability to sell non-competing products that the supplier deems ‘inappropriate’ assessed?

A restriction of this nature is likely to be assessed as an exclusive supply arrangement and prohibited if it causes or is likely to cause appreciable adverse effect on competition in India.

In M/s Fx Enterprise Solutions India Pvt Ltd and Anr v Hyundai Motor India Limited (Case Nos. 36 and 82 of 2014) (Hyundai), the CCI assessed a circular issued by Hyundai Motor India Limited to its dealers directing them to purchase engine oil from only two designated vendors: Indian Oil Corporation Limited and Shell Oil Company. This, according to the CCI, limited dealers’ choice in procuring engine oil from alternate suppliers. The CCI, however, found this restriction to be objectively justifiable, and noted that since the customers could in fact procure engine oil from other suppliers, there was no risk of appreciable adverse effect on competition.

In Vishal Pande v Honda Motorcycle and Scooter India Private Ltd, the CCI initiated an investigation into various allegations against Honda Motorcycle and Scooter India Private Limited (HMSIPL). One such allegation relates to a condition that required HMSIPL’s dealers to source oil and lubricants, batteries, accessories, merchandise items and insurance and finance services only from designated sources. The CCI suggested that this could create barriers for suppliers of oil and lubricants, batteries, etc, restrict consumer choice, result in higher prices and thereby lead to appreciable adverse effect on competition.

Explain how restricting the buyer’s ability to stock products competing with those supplied by the supplier under the agreement is assessed.

A restriction of this nature is likely to be assessed as an exclusive supply arrangement and will be prohibited if it causes, or is likely to cause, appreciable adverse effect on competition in India. In Hyundai, for example, the CCI examined restrictions imposed by Hyundai Motor India Limited that prevented its dealers from investing in other businesses without Hyundai Motor India Limited’s consent. As this condition only required the prior consent of Hyundai Motor India Limited, the CCI did not consider it to be akin to an exclusivity condition. Moreover, since several dealers did in fact operate dealerships of competing brands, the CCI did not find de facto exclusivity either. The CCI also recognised that this condition was perhaps necessary to prevent free-riding and continued commercial viability of the dealerships, by restraining the dealers from diverting funds meant for dealing in Hyundai Motor India Limited’s vehicles for other usages. That said, this decision of the CCI was set aside by the appellate court.

How is requiring the buyer to purchase from the supplier a certain amount or minimum percentage of the contract products or a full range of the supplier’s products assessed?

The CCI may prohibit a minimum off-take requirement as a vertical restriction if it causes, or is likely to cause, appreciable adverse effect on competition in India. To our knowledge, the CCI does not appear to have dealt with minimum off-take requirements as a vertical restriction as yet. Such obligations, however, have been examined under the provisions dealing with abuse of dominance. For example, in Faridabad Industries v Adani Gas Limited, the CCI assessed whether a minimum off-take obligation on the buyer amounted to an abusive term. While the CCI appreciated various business justifications associated with such contractual terms, it held that requiring the buyer to fulfil such minimum off-take obligations, even in the event of emergency shutdown, makes the term ‘unfair’ and hence abusive.

Explain how restricting the supplier’s ability to supply to other buyers is assessed.

Restricting the supplier’s ability to supply to other buyers is likely to be assessed by the CCI as refusal to deal or exclusive distribution agreement and prohibited if such restriction causes or is likely to cause appreciable adverse effect on competition in India. In Shamsher Kataria v Honda Siel Cars India Ltd (Case No. 3 of 2011), for example, certain automobile manufacturers restricted spare parts suppliers’ ability to sell spare parts produced by them directly to third parties. On account of such restrictions, the CCI considered each automobile manufacturer to wield significant market power in the market for supply of genuine spare parts, and found this restriction to have foreclosed the automobile repair market for independent repairers.

Explain how restricting the supplier’s ability to sell directly to end-consumers is assessed.

Restricting the supplier’s ability to supply to end-consumers is likely to be assessed by the CCI as refusal to deal or exclusive distribution agreement and prohibited if such restriction causes or is likely to cause appreciable adverse effect on competition in India. In Shamsher Kataria v Honda Siel Cars India Ltd (Case No. 3 of 2011), for example, certain automobile manufacturers restricted spare parts suppliers’ ability to sell spare parts produced by them directly to third parties. On account of such restrictions, the CCI considered each automobile manufacturer to wield significant market power in the market for supply of genuine spare parts, and found this restriction to have foreclosed the automobile repair market for independent repairers.

Have guidelines or agency decisions in your jurisdiction dealt with the antitrust assessment of restrictions on suppliers other than those covered above? If so, what were the restrictions in question and how were they assessed?

The CCI can assess any vertical agreement so long as it forecloses competition in India. Apart from the restrictions covered above, provisions on vertical restriction in India also extend to anticompetitive tying and bundling. Anticompetitive tying must satisfy the following conditions (Sonam Sharma v Apple Inc (Case No. 24 of 2011)):

> the presence of two separate products or services capable of being tied;
the seller must have sufficient economic power with respect to the tying product to appreciably restrain free competition in the market for the tied product; and
> the tying arrangement must affect a substantial amount of commerce.

In Vishal Pande v Honda Motorcycle and Scooter India Private Ltd, the CCI, inter alia, initiated investigation into a tie-in arrangement, whereby a certain advertising cost is debited from the dealers’ accounts on the basis of the number of vehicles dispatched to them. The CCI has suggested that this could create entry barriers for other advertising agencies.

Notification

Notifying agreements

Outline any formal procedure for notifying agreements containing vertical restraints to the authority responsible for antitrust enforcement.

The Competition Act does not provide a framework to pre-notify an agreement to the Competition Commission of India (or any other authority). As such, enterprises must carry out competition assessment of vertical restrictions themselves (and, if required, with the assistance of legal counsel).

Authority guidance

If there is no formal procedure for notification, is it possible to obtain guidance from the authority responsible for antitrust enforcement or a declaratory judgment from a court as to the assessment of a particular agreement in certain circumstances?

No. The Competition Commission of India does not provide formal or informal guidance in respect of behavioural conduct. It routinely publishes competition compliance manuals, advocacy booklets, FAQs, etc, which enterprises may use to align their practices with the Competition Act.

Enforcement

Complaints procedure for private partiesIs there a procedure whereby private parties can complain to the authority responsible for antitrust enforcement about alleged unlawful vertical restraints?

Yes. The Competition Commission of India (CCI) can enquire into allegations of behavioural contraventions (ie, cartels, vertical foreclosure or abuse of dominance) on its own, on receipt of ‘information’ from any person, consumer or their association or trade association, or by way of a reference made to it by government (informant). Broadly, the following procedure and timelines are followed:

> the filing of information: after the filing of information, the CCI scrutinises the information for any procedural deficiencies within 15 days. The informant remedies the defects within the prescribed timelines. The CCI has now revised filing fees for the filing of information;
> formation of a prima facie view by the CCI and initiation of investigation: the CCI endeavours to conclude its preliminary assessment within 60 days – at times after hearing the parties (which, in practice, takes longer than this). If the CCI finds prima facie contravention, it directs the Director General to carry out a detailed investigation. Otherwise, it closes the matter;
> investigation by the Director General: the Director General is required to submit its investigation report to the CCI within 60 days. This may be extended by the CCI up to a ‘reasonable period’ on the Director General’s request. In practice, the Director General routinely requests multiple extensions from the CCI, and its investigation could take any time between a few months to two to three years; and
> CCI’s review of the report of the Director General and final order: parties provide their comments to the Director General’s report typically within 30 days of receiving the report. Parties are then heard. As far as possible, the CCI is required to pass its final order within 21 working days of the date of conclusion of the hearings. This process also typically takes much longer than 21 working days.

Regulatory enforcement

How frequently is antitrust law applied to vertical restraints by the authority responsible for antitrust enforcement? What are the main enforcement priorities regarding vertical restraints?

A vast majority of the Competition Commission of India (CCI)’s decisions to date relate to cartels and abuse of dominance. In all the infringement decisions issued by the CCI, we estimate that less than 5 per cent of the cases relate to vertical restraints.

What are the consequences of an infringement of antitrust law for the validity or enforceability of a contract containing prohibited vertical restraints?

Vertical restrictions that cause, or are likely to cause, an appreciable adverse effect on competition in India are prohibited and considered void. That said, a vertical restriction found to be anticompetitive by the CCI in an otherwise valid contract is unlikely to render the entire contract unenforceable. In the context of contract law, the Supreme Court of India has recognised that if one part of a contract is rendered unenforceable, lawful parts may still be enforced, provided they are severable (Shin Satellite Public Co Ltd v Jain Studios Ltd (2006) 2 SCC 628)).

May the authority responsible for antitrust enforcement directly impose penalties or must it petition another entity? What sanctions and remedies can the authorities impose? What notable sanctions or remedies have been imposed? Can any trends be identified in this regard?

The CCI has the authority to directly penalise erring enterprises and does not need to approach a court for enforcement of its decisions. For anticompetitive vertical restrictions, the CCI can levy a penalty of up to 10 per cent per cent of the average relevant turnover for three preceding financial years (from the date of the CCI’s decision) of the contravening enterprise. Equally, the CCI may direct the erring enterprise to cease and desist from carrying on with the anticompetitive vertical restraint and change their business practices. Notably, the CCI can also penalise the individual office bearers responsible for the conduct of the business of the enterprise found guilty of contravening the provisions of the Competition Act.

Investigative powers of the authority

What investigative powers does the authority responsible for antitrust enforcement have when enforcing the prohibition of vertical restraints?

The Competition Commission of India (CCI) and the Director General have powers of a civil court for the purpose of discharging their functions under the Competition Act in respect of the following matters:

> summoning and enforcing the attendance of any person and examining them on oath;
> requiring the discovery and production of documents;
> receiving evidence on affidavit;
> issuing requests for examination of witnesses or documents; and
> requisitioning public records or documents from any office.

The CCI may also call upon experts from disciplines such as economics, commerce, accountancy and international trade to assist in its inquiry. The Director General also has the power to conduct dawn raids. The CCI and the Director General can, and often do, investigate enterprises domiciled outside India. In fact, the CCI is also empowered to investigate and restrain anticompetitive acts or agreements taking place outside India but having an appreciable adverse effect on competition in India.

Private enforcement

To what extent is private enforcement possible? Can non-parties to agreements containing vertical restraints obtain declaratory judgments or injunctions and bring damages claims? Can the parties to agreements themselves bring damages claims? What remedies are available? How long should a company expect a private enforcement action to take?

Competition law enforcement in India is not adversarial. Accordingly, declaratory judgments or injunctions and claims for damages in the traditional sense are not possible in India. However, as a regulator, the Competition Commission of India (CCI) is duty bound to examine any information provided by any person or government body to assess whether it warrants a detailed examination. Such information can be provided by parties to the agreements themselves. Also, while doing so, if an informant can establish that the alleged anticompetitive conduct is likely to be established upon detailed investigation and continuation of such conduct pending CCI’s investigation could cause irreparable harm, the CCI may also grant an interim injunction against such anticompetitive conduct.

Once the CCI has reached a finding of infringement, any person aggrieved by the anticompetitive conduct of the infringing firm may approach the appellate authority, the National Company Appellate Tribunal, seeking compensation for the loss suffered owing to the anticompetitive conduct. In practice though, such claims are rare and usually not processed until the infringing firm has exhausted its appellate remedies.

Other issues

Other issues

Is there any unique point relating to the assessment of vertical restraints in your jurisdiction that is not covered above?

All significant points relating to the assessment of vertical restrictions in India have been covered above.

Update and trends

Recent developments

What were the most significant two or three decisions or developments in this area in the last 12 months?

Recent developments:

2019 saw nine closure decisions from the Competition Commission of India (CCI) and three cases where the CCI initiated investigations based on a prima facie view that the alleged conduct disclosed an anticompetitive vertical relationship. While the investigation initiated in the Maruti Suzuki India Limited case revolved around allegations of imposing discount-related restrictions enforced by levy of penalties for non-compliance, the decision in Matrix Info Systems Private Limited v Intel Corporation & Ors (Case No. 05 of 2019) appears to be the first decision that substantially covers how parallel imports will be treated under the Competition Act.

The decision in MakeMyTrip is noteworthy as the CCI disagreed with its earlier decision (issued in 2017) based on an overall consideration of the market realities and rapidly changing competition dynamics. The CCI observed that, ‘while two and a half years may not be a period sufficiently long for traditional markets to undergo perceptible change, the pace of evolution of digital markets is significantly faster’ and ‘the intervening period has seen the online travel portals and the customised service that they provide to consumers on account of big data analytics to have established a distinct and significantly more prominent position in the hotel reservation space in India’.

Anticipated developments:

The government of India constituted a Competition Law Review Committee, which was mandated to propose amendments to the Competition Act (and the accompanying set of regulations) in order to make them consistent with strong economic fundamentals and international best practices. The Committee submitted its report to the concerned Ministry on 26 July 2019 recommending amendments to the Competition Act. Some of the salient features in the context of vertical agreements are:

The term ‘exclusive supply agreement’ should be substituted with the term ‘exclusive dealing’, since the definition of exclusive supply agreement under the Competition Act focuses on exclusivity imposed on a buyer by a seller and does not expressly cover the scenario of a buyer imposing exclusivity on a seller.

The term ‘resale price maintenance’ should expressly refer to both direct and indirect means of imposing resale price maintenance. Indirect means could include use of threats, the imposition of sanctions or penalties, or even through benefits such as promotional offers, when the resale price is in fact maintained by the seller.

In line with its objective to protect the interests of the consumer, the Competition Act should also take into account consumer harm while assessing the appreciable adverse effect on competition.

Authors:

Bharat Budholia, Partner
Akshat Kulshrestha, Senior Associate

AUTHORS & CONTRIBUTORS

TAGS

SHARE

DISCLAIMER

These are the views and opinions of the author(s) and do not necessarily reflect the views of the Firm. This article is intended for general information only and does not constitute legal or other advice and you acknowledge that there is no relationship (implied, legal or fiduciary) between you and the author/AZB. AZB does not claim that the article's content or information is accurate, correct or complete, and disclaims all liability for any loss or damage caused through error or omission.